Friday, August 17, 2007

Legion of doom

The goldbugs arrived today. m* received the latest "Greed and Fear" from the inimitable Christopher Wood of CLSA and immediately checked the stock of canned food in the cupboards. If ever m* thought about dipping into those REITS down 25% or doubted for a minute those decoupling skeptics and declaimers of fiat money, this latest cured all weakness.

And Bernard Connolly at AIG, the walking Wikipedia of economic theory classification, sends his best as well. Only 18 pages but the usual tasty seminar in history of economic thought, replete with footnotes taking up entire pages, awaits.

These latest missives on "The Crisis" and policy perspective are almost too good to share, and almost too scary not to. Unfortunately these are not yet in the public domain, as m* understands it anyway.

However, as an altogether safer (you can put the ammunition away), and possibly more sane option, m* offers a recent note from two prominent macro-economists on the question "what do we want from our central banks in this situation?"

The note is a response to Martin Wolf's appropriately titled scare-mongering FT column "Fear Makes a Welcome Return." Incidentally m* has noticed a clear pattern of commentary in the FT of late strongly advocating what m* calls the moralist case, (first described as such in notes from the folks at Toqueville - yep more goldbugs), which deems a puritanical cleansing of credit excess only fitting and stealthily argues for "free banking" ie: permitting bank failures, thus re-introducing the natural counterweight to animal spirits, moral hazard, back into the system. That is revolutionary stuff from our Socialist cousins across the pond.

This however is not. It is not even sensational. It is so sane as to be boring. Maybe we could use some of that right about now. Thank you, gentlemen.

Ricardo Caballero and Arvind Krishnamurthy: A liquidity crisis is taking place where investors, banks, and funds are scrambling for liquidity. Several hedge funds run by prominent investment banks in the US and abroad have liquidated or have suspended convertibility.

Paradoxically, when viewed as a whole there is sufficient liquidity in the financial system. Banks are well capitalised and flush with liquidity. Just a few weeks ago stock markets were soaring, investors were optimistic, and the VIX hit 13, not far from its 9.5 all time low. Yes, the residential real estate market in the US was declining and creating a mess in the subprime market.

But it was generally understood that the scale of these subprime losses was small in relation to the US and world economy. Even if all subprime mortgages and related CDOs were to lose all value, this would amount to just 2.5 per cent of US wealth. A more realistic, yet still pessimistic scenario puts the potential losses at $400bn, less than 1 per cent of US wealth. These losses could hardly have reversed the liquidity position of the financial sector. Hence, many pundits used the word "contained" in describing the subprime losses. Yet, it is clear that there is a liquidity crisis unfolding before our eyes.

Why? The reason is a rise in uncertainty - that is, a rise in unknown and immeasurable risk rather than the measurable risk that the financial sector specialises in managing. The financial instruments and derivative structures underpinning the recent growth in credit markets are complex. Market participants cannot refer to a historical record to measure how these financial structures will behave during a time of stress. Thus, today there is considerable uncertainty about who will and will not lose money in the credit market turmoil.

To understand how uncertainty can move an economy from excess liquidity to a liquidity crunch, an analogy might be useful. In the children’s game of musical chairs, when the music stops, only one child will be left without a seat. However if the children are confused about the rules and each is convinced that they will be the one left without a seat, chaos may erupt. Kids may start grabbing on to chairs, running backwards, etc.

In the same way, in today’s market uncertainty is leading every player to make decisions based on imagined worst-case scenarios. Market players that have the liquidity stay out of markets or pull back dramatically. But the financial markets need participants and their liquidity in order to function. When much of the market disengages due to uncertainty, the effective supply of liquidity in the financial system contracts. Those that need liquidity are unable to get it and financial markets turn illiquid.

What should central banks do in this case? They must find a way to re-engage the private sector's liquidity. Understanding that uncertainty is the cause of the disengagement is the start of finding the solution. A first step in reducing agents' uncertainty is for the central bank to clarify how it will act if agents’ worst case scenarios come to pass.

The central bank’s mission is to stabilise the economy as a whole and not individual participants. When viewed as a whole, the worst case scenarios that guide the behaviour of each market participant cannot simultaneously occur. Like musical chairs, when the music stops, only one child will be left without a seat, not every child.

The subprime shock at the end of the day is a small shock; it is only the actions of panicked investors that make it appear large. A central bank that understands this point will convincingly promise large liquidity injections in the event of a meltdown. The likelihood of having to deliver on the promise is minimal, but the reduced anxiety fostered by such a commitment restarts private liquidity circulation and helps restore normalcy.

It is important to understand that this is all about information and not about real liquidity additions. We do not have a true liquidity shortage on our hands; we only have one because of the reactions of an anxious private sector. Talking and providing information and certainty can go a long way to reducing uncertainty. A rate cut may be the right tool, but it is important not for its direct liquid addition, and instead for what it conveys about the central bank's readiness to act if things do get worse.

Will the Fed and other central banks around the world act appropriately? The early reactions are positive. The ECB was first to act, injecting more than $214bn in the last two days. The Fed followed with a more modest $38bn on Friday, and the rest of the central banks of the world did their share, lending over $73bn to the market.

It may also be that some of investors’ uncertainty stems from not knowing how Fed chairman Bernanke will react in case of a meltdown. Is he too much of an inflation targeter and oblivious to the workings of financial market? Not likely. From his extensive academic work on these matters, it is apparent that he is quite aware of the importance of credit markets to the functioning of the economy and the cost of the central bank failing to identify a liquidity event in time. It may well be time to start buying put options on the VIX.


Reference: R Caballero and A Krishnamurthy, "Collective Risk Management in a Flight to Quality Episode", forthcoming in The Journal of Finance

1 comment:

Anonymous said...

I can see that you are an expert at your field! I am launching a website soon, and your information will be very useful for me.. Thanks for all your help and wishing you all the success.